Skip to main content

Table 2 Results: Interest parity via long-bills of exchange

From: Interest-parity conditions during the era of the classical gold standard (1880–1914)—evidence from the investment demand for bills of exchange in Europe

 

Continental investment demand for London bills of exchange

 

London investment demand for continental bills of exchange

 

Paris

Amsterdam

Berlin

Brussels

 

London on

 

on London

 

Paris

Amsterdam

Berlin

Brussels

 

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

 

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

Intercept \(\left (\widehat {\alpha }\right)\)

0.003

0.01

0.01

0.001

 

0.01

0.01

0.01

0.01

 

(0.0004)

(0.001)

(0.001)

(0.001)

 

(0.002)

(0.002)

(0.002)

(0.003)

i \(_{t}^{*} \left (\widehat {\beta }\right)\)

1.01

0.97

0.96

1.05

     
 

(0.02)

(0.02)

(0.02)

(0.02)

     

i \(_{t} \left (\widehat {\beta }\right)\)

     

0.62

0.75

0.81

0.75

      

(0.05)

(0.07)

(0.06)

(0.09)

Reject (β=1)

  

**

***

 

***

***

***

***

R 2

0.81

0.84

0.87

0.90

 

0.30

0.33

0.39

0.37

N

1772

1759

1771

903

 

1759

1749

1759

890

  1. Notes: This table reports estimates of Eq. (3) with dependent variable \(l_{t}-s_{t}^{*}\) and (4) with dependent variable \(l_{t}-s_{t+m}^{*}\) (expressed as annualised value). Estimation is by OLS with heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust (Newey-West) standard errors with a fixed bandwidth of 13 leads and lags. The null hypothesis that the interest parity (via long-bill transactions) holds implies that β=1N the number of observations Significant deviations from this are indicated by ** at the 5% level, and *** at the 1% level